Search the site by keyword

Reading past the job-loss headlines

27 June 2019
Houston café

“Machines take jobs” cry the headlines. A journalist friend once said the media only publish two stories: “it’s that terrible” and “isn’t that wonderful”. “Machines take jobs” is clearly “terrible”. But its logical opposite, “machines create jobs”, is unlikely to make the grade as “wonderful”. Such selection effects mean that bad news crowds out the good.

Today I’m going to look at just one such headline: Exclusive: Amazon rolls out machines that pack orders and replace jobs. Reading past such a headline tells us a more nuanced story. When we hear about job losses our concerns naturally turn to those losing the jobs. But, without further information, we may also assume that the direct job loss figures also accurately describe the aggregate labour market effects. This post makes the general point that

while the direct labour market effects of tech adoption are salient, the many and varied indirect effects are significant and can overwhelm or reverse the direct effects in aggregate.

Aggregate impacts are only part of a wider whole story. Jobs created may not match those lost in location, wage levels or skills requirements. Such mismatches can make it much harder for affected workers. But the aggregate story is important. Finding a new job in a buoyant labour market is very different from finding one in a depressed market. This post explores aggregate impacts, with the intention of informing future posts on individual, local and distributional impacts.

Let’s start with the direct, or first-order, effect: “Amazon.com Inc is rolling out machines to automate a job held by thousands of its workers: boxing up customer orders … Amazon has considered installing two machines at dozens more warehouses, removing at least 24 roles at each one ... That would amount to more than 1,300 cuts across 55 U.S. fulfillment centers”. Let’s call that 110 machines at 55 plants leading to 1300 jobs lost – clearly headline material. 

But machines need people too! “The machines require one person to load customer orders, [and] another to stock cardboard and glue ...” This is a second-order effect, which, based on the description in the article, might create 220 jobs. Further, “these machines are not without flaws … They need a technician on site who can fix problems as they arise”, which would mean a further 55 jobs. There’s a lot of guesswork going on, but let’s call that 275 jobs created. This is a second-order effect.

Will Amazon fire 1300 existing workers and hire 275 new ones? That’s unclear. Taking Amazon at their word, “rather than lay off workers, [they] will one day refrain from refilling packing roles. Those have high turnover because boxing multiple orders per minute over 10 hours is taxing work. At the same time, employees that stay with the company can be trained to take up more technical roles.” It’s at least conceivable that the combination of voluntary attrition and retraining could avoid any forced redundancies. I’d want to know more about turnover rates and Amazon’s history as an employer before making any predictions.

What about effects outside of Amazon? Well, the machines cost $1m each. It takes people to design, build and install million-dollar machines. An Italian firm supplies the machines, so perhaps many of those jobs are offshore, which complicates the story (but not the overall maths). How many jobs? I will punt up a guestimate of 200.1 But this is another second-order effect. Together, second order effects drop the original job-losses of 1300 down to a net 825.

These first- and second-order effects are “mechanical”, in the sense that they are consequences of purchasing, installing and operating the new machines. But such changes also affect costs, revenue and hence profits, that is, they have economiceffects. I’ll call such effects “third order”. The article hints at them when it says: “Amazon would expect to recover the costs in under two years”.

After those two years, Amazon will presumably be earning additional profits. Let’s consider four cases for who receives the benefits.

  • Customers (by dropping prices). Customers have more money to spend, including at Amazon. With lower prices, Amazon’s overall sales will likely rise. And that would require more staff at Amazon and at its suppliers. And perhaps more boxing machines!
  • New workers (by improving customer service or quality). Amazon will need more workers to implement that improvement. And customers will be better off as they get more for their dollar. By offering better value, Amazon’s overall sales could rise – requiring further staff at Amazon and at its suppliers.
  • Existing workers (by increasing wages). Workers have more money to spend. Presumably little of this gets spent at Amazon, so they won’t directly benefit. But wherever it is spent, it will create jobs.
  • Investors (by increasing dividends). Investors are people too, and their spending creates further jobs.

Which of these cases will apply? That’s hard to say. Amazon has a long history of preferring to build its business rather than rewards its investors. So, the first three cases seem more likely. The article hints towards new workers (“We expect the efficiency savings will be re-invested in new services for customers, where new jobs will continue to be created”), and to existing workers (“the company … raised wages to attract staff in a tight labor market”).

Whichever case (or combination of cases) applies, jobs are created, not destroyed. How many? Would they create more than the net 875 jobs lost through first and second order effects? I’ve mined all I can from the article, so don’t have the information to inform a prediction.

However, increasing incomes and falling prices for goods both tend to increase the consumption of services. And service production, in general, is more labour intensive than goods production. Technology-created profits will create jobs, whether in the hands of workers, investors or customers. This is one of the reasons previous rounds of labour-replacing technology has not led to mass unemployment.

More generally, the profits generated by a cost-reducing technology gives a firm two options: to reduce prices to attract increased sales or to redistribute those profits. The labour market effects both options are positive, though different. Economic theory tells us that this choice is driven by the firm’s cost structure and by market conditions (specifically the demand elasticity) for the firm’s output.

It has become common to hear people distinguish between labour-replacing and labour-augmenting technologies. Clearly all automation technologies are labour-replacing, if we only consider the first- and second-order effects. But one must also include the third-order effects to decide whether a specific application of a technology will be, on net, labour-augmenting. Importantly, that outcome is not an attribute of the technology, per se; rather it depends on the specific application. So, I would argue that it is misleading to apply the adjectives “labour-replacing” and “labour-augmenting” to technology.

This leads us to a second general message:

A specific technology might have very different labour market effects when applied in one industry than it has in another, or in one consumer market rather than another. This could undermine a policy response that tried to differentiate based on the characteristics of the technology alone.

In this post I’ve shown how a job-loss headline figure of 1300 drops to 875 once second-order effects are included, and why it will drop further – and perhaps become positive – following third order effects. Next time you read a “machine takes jobs” headline, take some time to think about first, second and third-order effects. Should that headline be saying “machines create jobs”?  

Notes

1. Roughly two jobs per machine, assuming that labour costs are 50% of revenues, an average annual wage of US$75,000 and a 7-year machine life.

Photo: Tablets at every seat replace waiters and cashiers at a Houston café. Source: Dave Heatley.

Have your say

Please tick the box to prove you're a human and help us stop spam.

Comments

  • Gravatar for Paul Brophy

    Paul Brophy 8/07/2019, 2:22 pm (4 years ago)

    Great article, I think there's a lot of scaremongering at the moment and unfortunately many of us buy into that. Thanks for quanitifying some of the supposed facts :-)

    Please tick the box to prove you're a human and help us stop spam.

RSS feed for comments on this page | RSS feed for all comments